Government actions in externalities

Get the most by viewing this topic in your current grade. Pick your course now.

?
Intros
Lessons
  1. Government Actions in Externalities Overview
  2. How Government Regulates Negative Externalities
    • Property Rights
    • Taxes
    • Emissions Charges
    • Cap-and-Trade
  3. Using Pollution Tax for Negative Externalities
    • Add Tax to MC curve
    • S = MC + tax
    • Supply curve = Marginal social curve
    • Optimal social output achieved
    • Government gains Tax revenue
  4. How Government Regulates Positive Externalities
    • Public Production
    • Subsidies
    • Vouchers
    • Patents & Copyrights
  5. Using Subsidies for Positive Externalities
    • Subtract Marginal Social Cost with Subsidy
    • S1 = MSC - subsidy
    • Market Equilibrium at intersection of S1 & MB
    • Quantity same as optimal social output
?
Examples
Lessons
  1. Questions Relating to Negative Externalities
    Suppose a firm produces pesticides, but it also produces wastes which they dump into a lake. The following table shows the demand schedule and marginal cost for pesticides. Assume that the marginal external cost is equal to the marginal cost.

    Price

    Quantity

    Marginal Cost

    4

    50

    10

    8

    40

    8

    12

    30

    6

    16

    20

    4

    20

    10

    2


    1. If there are no regulations for the waste, what is the quantity and price of pesticides produced? What is the marginal external cost?
    2. If residents now have property rights for the lake, how would the firm change its quantity and price of pesticides?
  2. Suppose a firm produces greenhouse gas emissions for a product. The following graph shows the marginal social benefit and marginal private cost. Assume the marginal external cost is 4.

    Government Actions in Externalities

    1. If there are no regulations for the greenhouse gas emissions, what is the quantity and price of pesticides produced?
    2. The government implements a caps-and-trade to the product. What would be the maximum quantity set by the government to reduce greenhouse gas emissions?
    3. With caps-and-trade, what would the price of the product be? When do firms stop trading permits?
  3. Suppose a firm produces goods that pollutes a river nearby. The following table shows the demand schedule and marginal cost for the good. Assume that the marginal external cost is equal to the marginal cost.

    Price

    Quantity

    Marginal Cost

    2

    125

    5

    4

    100

    4

    6

    75

    3

    8

    50

    2

    10

    25

    1


    1. If there are no government actions to control pollution, what is the quantity and price of goods produced, and the marginal external cost of the pollution generated?
    2. If the government levies a pollution tax, what would the efficient quantity and price be for the good?
    3. What is the tax levied?
    4. What is the government tax revenue per day?
  4. Questions Relating to Positive Externalities
    The marginal cost of educating a student is a constant $2,000 a year, and the following table shows the student's marginal benefit curve. University education has an external benefits of $1,000 per student per year.

    Price (of Tuition in thousands)

    Quantity (student's per year in thousands)

    5

    50

    4

    100

    3

    150

    2

    200

    1

    250


    1. If all universities are private, and the education market is competitive, then what is the tuition and the number of students enrolled per year?
    2. If the government creates public universities, what tuition will universities charge and taxpayers pay to achieve an efficient number of students?
  5. The marginal cost of educating a student is a constant $2,000 a year, and the following table shows the student's marginal benefit curve. University education has an external benefit of $1,000 per student per year.

    Price (of Tuition in thousands)

    Quantity (student's per year in thousands)

    5

    50

    4

    100

    3

    150

    2

    200

    1

    250


    1. If the government decides to subsidize private universities, what subsidy would achieve the efficient number of university students?
    2. If the government offers vouchers to students who enroll into universities with no subsidy, what should the value of the voucher be to achieve the efficient number of university students?
Topic Notes
?

Introduction: Government Actions in Externalities

Government actions play a crucial role in addressing externalities, which are the unintended effects of economic activities on third parties. The introduction video provides a comprehensive overview of this topic, serving as an essential foundation for understanding the complexities of externalities and their impact on society. By watching this video, viewers will gain insights into how governments intervene to mitigate negative externalities and promote positive ones. Negative externalities, such as pollution, require government intervention through regulations or taxes to reduce their harmful effects. Conversely, positive externalities, like education or public health initiatives, often need government support to maximize their benefits to society. The video emphasizes the importance of balancing these actions to achieve optimal outcomes. By exploring various government strategies, including subsidies, taxes, and regulations, viewers will develop a deeper understanding of how policymakers address externalities to promote economic efficiency and social welfare.

Addressing Negative Externalities

Negative externalities are costs or harmful effects that economic activities impose on third parties not directly involved in the transaction. These external costs are not reflected in the market price of goods or services, leading to market inefficiencies. Governments employ various methods to address negative externalities and internalize these external costs, ensuring that the true social cost of production is accounted for.

One fundamental approach to addressing negative externalities is through the establishment and enforcement of property rights. When property rights are clearly defined and enforced, individuals or entities have the legal authority to control and benefit from their resources. This can help mitigate externalities by allowing affected parties to negotiate with those causing the externality. For example, if a factory is polluting a nearby river, clearly defined property rights would allow downstream property owners to negotiate with or sue the factory for damages, incentivizing the factory to reduce its pollution.

Taxes are another powerful tool used by governments to address negative externalities. By imposing taxes on activities that generate negative externalities, governments can increase the private cost of these activities to match their social cost. This approach, often called Pigouvian taxation after economist Arthur Pigou, aims to discourage harmful activities by making them more expensive. For instance, a carbon tax on fossil fuels increases their cost, encouraging businesses and consumers to reduce their carbon emissions and seek cleaner alternatives. The revenue generated from these taxes can be used to mitigate the externality's effects or fund research into cleaner technologies.

Emission charges are a specific form of taxation designed to address pollution-related externalities. These charges are levied on polluters based on the amount of emissions they produce. By putting a price on pollution, emission charges create a direct financial incentive for firms to reduce their emissions. For example, a factory might be charged for each ton of sulfur dioxide it releases into the atmosphere. This encourages the factory to invest in cleaner technologies or adjust its production processes to minimize emissions and reduce its charges. Emission charges effectively internalize the external costs of pollution by making polluters pay for the environmental damage they cause.

Cap and trade systems represent a market-based approach to addressing negative externalities, particularly in the context of emissions reduction. Under this system, the government sets a cap on the total amount of a specific pollutant that can be emitted. It then issues a limited number of permits or allowances, each representing the right to emit a certain amount of the pollutant. Companies can trade these permits among themselves, creating a market for emissions. Those who can reduce emissions cheaply may sell their excess permits to companies for whom emissions reduction is more expensive. The European Union Emissions Trading System (EU ETS) is a prominent example of a cap and trade system aimed at reducing greenhouse gas emissions.

The cap and trade approach offers several advantages. It provides flexibility for businesses to find the most cost-effective ways to reduce emissions, encourages innovation in clean technologies, and ensures that the overall emission target is met. As the cap is gradually lowered over time, the price of permits typically increases, further incentivizing emissions reduction.

All these methods - property rights, taxes, emission charges, and cap and trade systems - aim to internalize external costs by making those responsible for negative externalities bear the full cost of their actions. This internalization process aligns private incentives with social welfare, leading to more efficient resource allocation and reduced negative impacts on society and the environment.

For instance, when a factory is required to pay for its pollution through taxes or emission charges, it is more likely to invest in cleaner production methods or reduce output to a socially optimal level. Similarly, when a cap and trade system limits the total emissions in an industry, companies are compelled to factor the cost of emissions into their business decisions, leading to more environmentally friendly practices.

In conclusion, addressing negative externalities is crucial for promoting economic efficiency and social welfare. By employing a combination of property rights enforcement, targeted taxation, emission charges, and market-based mechanisms like cap and trade systems, governments can effectively internalize external costs and guide economic activities towards more sustainable and socially beneficial outcomes. These approaches not only discourage harmful activities but also stimulate innovation and the development of cleaner technologies, paving the way for a more sustainable economic future.

Using Pollution Tax for Negative Externalities

Pollution tax is a powerful economic tool designed to address negative externalities, particularly environmental pollution. This mechanism works by internalizing the external costs of pollution, effectively aligning the private costs of production with the social costs borne by society. By implementing a pollution tax, policymakers aim to create a more efficient market equilibrium and reduce deadweight loss.

To understand how a pollution tax functions, it's essential to examine its graphical representation and the shift from marginal private cost (MPC) to marginal social cost (MSC). This process can be broken down into several steps:

  1. Initial Market Equilibrium: Before the tax, the market equilibrium is determined by the intersection of the demand curve and the marginal private cost curve. This point represents the quantity produced and consumed when firms only consider their private costs.
  2. Identifying the Marginal Social Cost: The marginal social cost curve lies above the marginal private cost curve, reflecting the additional costs imposed on society by pollution. The vertical distance between these curves represents the external cost per unit of production.
  3. Implementing the Pollution Tax: A tax equal to the external cost per unit is imposed on producers. This tax effectively shifts the MPC curve upward, aligning it with the MSC curve.
  4. New Market Equilibrium: The intersection of the demand curve and the new, shifted supply curve (which now includes the tax) determines the new market equilibrium. This point represents the socially optimal level of production and consumption.

The concept of efficient market equilibrium is crucial in understanding the effectiveness of a pollution tax. An efficient market equilibrium occurs when the marginal social benefit equals the marginal social cost. In the context of pollution, this equilibrium is achieved when the price consumers pay reflects both the private costs of production and the social costs of pollution.

The shift from the initial equilibrium to the efficient market equilibrium results in several key outcomes:

  • Reduced production and consumption of the polluting good
  • Higher market price, reflecting the true social cost
  • Internalization of external costs
  • Incentives for firms to adopt cleaner technologies or production methods

One of the primary benefits of achieving an efficient market equilibrium through a pollution tax is the reduction of deadweight loss. Deadweight loss represents the economic inefficiency caused by market failure, in this case, the negative externality of pollution. By implementing a pollution tax, the deadweight loss is minimized as the market moves towards the socially optimal level of production and consumption.

The relationship between efficient market equilibrium and deadweight loss reduction can be explained as follows:

  1. Without intervention, the market produces too much of the polluting good, resulting in a deadweight loss to society.
  2. The pollution tax corrects this market failure by internalizing the external costs.
  3. As production decreases to the socially optimal level, the deadweight loss is eliminated or significantly reduced.
  4. The tax revenue generated can potentially be used to mitigate environmental damage or fund clean energy initiatives.

It's important to note that while a pollution tax can be highly effective in theory, its practical implementation can be challenging. Policymakers must carefully consider factors such as determining the appropriate tax rate, monitoring emissions, and addressing potential impacts on competitiveness and income distribution. Despite these challenges, pollution taxes remain a valuable tool in the arsenal of environmental policy instruments, helping to align economic incentives with environmental sustainability goals.

In conclusion, pollution taxes work by shifting the marginal private cost curve to reflect the true social cost of production, creating a new, efficient market equilibrium. This mechanism effectively internalizes negative externalities, reduces deadweight loss, and provides incentives for cleaner production methods. By understanding and implementing pollution taxes, policymakers can work towards a more sustainable and economically efficient future.

Addressing Positive Externalities

Positive externalities occur when the production or consumption of a good or service generates benefits for third parties who are not directly involved in the transaction. These external benefits are not reflected in the market price, leading to an underproduction of the good or service from a societal perspective. To address this market failure and maximize social welfare, governments employ various methods to internalize these external benefits and increase production to socially optimal levels.

One primary method used by governments is public production. This involves the government directly producing and providing goods or services that generate positive externalities. For example, public education is a classic case of public production addressing positive externalities. Education not only benefits the individual receiving it but also society as a whole through increased productivity, reduced crime rates, and improved civic engagement. By providing public education, the government ensures that these broader societal benefits are realized at a level closer to the social optimum.

Another crucial tool in addressing positive externalities is the use of subsidies. Subsidies are financial incentives provided by the government to producers or consumers to encourage the production or consumption of goods with positive externalities. For instance, governments often subsidize renewable energy production to promote cleaner air and reduce greenhouse gas emissions. These subsidies lower the cost of production for renewable energy companies, allowing them to offer their products at more competitive prices and increase overall production. This approach helps internalize the external benefits of reduced pollution and climate change mitigation.

Vouchers represent a third method governments use to address positive externalities. Vouchers are government-issued credits that can be used to purchase specific goods or services. This approach allows the government to support the consumption of goods with positive externalities while still maintaining some level of consumer choice. A prime example is school vouchers, where the government provides families with vouchers to be used towards education expenses at a school of their choice. This system aims to increase access to quality education, which generates positive externalities for society, while still allowing for market competition and individual preferences in school selection.

Each of these methods - public production, subsidies, and vouchers - aims to increase the production or consumption of goods and services with positive externalities to a level closer to the social optimum. By doing so, they help internalize the external benefits that would otherwise be overlooked in a purely market-driven system.

Public production directly ensures the provision of goods with positive externalities, often at a scale that private markets would not achieve. This method is particularly effective for goods that are difficult to exclude people from using, such as public parks or national defense. Subsidies, on the other hand, work within the existing market structure by altering the incentives for private producers or consumers. They can be more flexible than public production and allow for continued private sector innovation. Vouchers offer a middle ground, providing government support while maintaining consumer choice and market competition.

It's important to note that the choice between these methods often depends on the specific characteristics of the good or service in question, as well as political and economic considerations. For example, public production might be preferred for goods that are essential and universally needed, like basic education or public health services. Subsidies might be more appropriate for industries where private sector innovation is crucial, such as renewable energy technology. Vouchers could be favored in situations where consumer choice is valued highly, but the government still wants to encourage consumption of goods with positive externalities.

In conclusion, addressing positive externalities is crucial for maximizing social welfare. Through public production, subsidies, and vouchers, governments can help internalize external benefits and increase the production or consumption of goods and services that benefit society as a whole. By implementing these methods, policymakers aim to bridge the gap between private market outcomes and socially optimal levels of production, ultimately leading to a more efficient and beneficial allocation of resources in society.

Using Subsidies for Positive Externalities

Subsidies play a crucial role in addressing positive externalities, which occur when the production or consumption of a good or service benefits third parties not directly involved in the transaction. Understanding how subsidies work to correct market inefficiencies is essential for policymakers and economists alike. This detailed explanation will break down the process, focusing on the graphical representation and its implications.

To begin, let's consider a market with a positive externality. In such a scenario, the marginal private demand (MPD) curve represents the benefits perceived by individual consumers, while the marginal social demand (MSD) curve accounts for both private and external benefits. The gap between these two curves illustrates the positive externality.

Without government intervention, the market equilibrium occurs where the MPD curve intersects the supply curve. However, this equilibrium is inefficient as it doesn't account for the external benefits. To correct this, the government can introduce a subsidy.

Here's a step-by-step breakdown of how subsidies work graphically:

  1. Identify the initial supply curve (S1) and the market equilibrium point where it intersects with the MPD curve.
  2. Determine the efficient quantity, which occurs where the MSD curve intersects with the supply curve.
  3. Calculate the appropriate subsidy amount, which should equal the vertical distance between the MPD and MSD curves at the efficient quantity.
  4. Shift the supply curve downward by the amount of the subsidy, creating a new supply curve (S2).
  5. The new equilibrium point is where S2 intersects with the MPD curve, which should align with the efficient quantity.

The shift in the supply curve is crucial. By lowering the cost of production through subsidies, the government encourages producers to increase output. This shift effectively internalizes the positive externality, aligning private incentives with social benefits.

The concept of efficient quantity is central to this process. It represents the output level where marginal social benefits equal marginal costs. At this point, society maximizes its net benefit from the good or service. By using subsidies to achieve this quantity, policymakers can eliminate the deadweight loss associated with underproduction in the presence of positive externalities.

Deadweight loss occurs when the market fails to produce at the socially optimal level. In the case of positive externalities, it represents the potential social benefits that are foregone due to underproduction. By shifting the supply curve to intersect with the MPD curve at the efficient quantity, subsidies effectively eliminate this deadweight loss.

It's important to note that determining the correct subsidy amount requires accurate information about the magnitude of the positive externality. Policymakers must carefully assess the external benefits to ensure the subsidy precisely bridges the gap between private and social demand.

While subsidies can be an effective tool for addressing positive externalities, they are not without challenges. Funding for subsidies typically comes from tax revenues, which can create distortions in other parts of the economy. Additionally, there's a risk of over-subsidization if the externality is overestimated, potentially leading to inefficient resource allocation.

In conclusion, subsidies work to address positive externalities by shifting the supply curve to align market outcomes with socially optimal levels of production. By understanding the graphical representation and the concept of efficient quantity, policymakers can design effective interventions to maximize social welfare and eliminate deadweight loss. However, careful analysis and implementation are crucial to ensure that the benefits of subsidies outweigh their potential drawbacks.

Comparing Government Actions on Externalities

Government actions to address externalities, both negative and positive, are crucial for maintaining economic efficiency and social welfare. When comparing approaches for these different types of externalities, several key similarities and differences emerge in terms of their effectiveness, challenges, and appropriateness.

For negative externalities, such as pollution, governments often employ taxes, regulations, or cap-and-trade systems. These methods aim to internalize the external costs and discourage harmful activities. On the other hand, positive externalities, like education or public provision of goods and services to encourage beneficial activities.

One similarity in the approaches is that both seek to align private incentives with social benefits. However, the mechanisms differ significantly. Taxes on negative externalities increase costs for producers, while subsidies for positive externalities reduce costs for consumers or providers. Both methods can be effective in theory, but their success depends on accurate valuation of the externality and proper implementation.

The effectiveness of these actions varies. Taxes and regulations on negative externalities can yield quick results if set at appropriate levels, but may face resistance from affected industries. Subsidies for positive externalities often have broader public support but may take longer to show measurable impacts. Cap-and-trade systems for negative externalities and public provision of goods offer market-based and direct approaches, respectively, each with their own strengths in flexibility or control.

Challenges in addressing externalities are numerous. For negative externalities, difficulties include accurately measuring the social cost, enforcing regulations, and preventing unintended consequences like industry relocation. Positive externality interventions face challenges in determining the optimal level of support, ensuring efficient use of public funds, and avoiding over-reliance on government assistance.

The appropriateness of each method depends on various factors. Taxes and regulations are often suitable for widespread negative externalities with clear sources, like carbon emissions. Cap-and-trade systems work well for externalities that can be quantified and traded, such as pollution credits. Subsidies are appropriate for positive externalities where the social benefit significantly outweighs the private benefit, as in basic research. Direct provision is often chosen for essential positive externalities like public education or healthcare.

In conclusion, while government actions for negative and positive externalities share the goal of aligning private and social interests, they differ significantly in their approaches. The effectiveness and appropriateness of each method depend on the specific externality, market conditions, and political context. Policymakers must carefully consider these factors to choose the most suitable intervention for each situation, balancing economic efficiency with social welfare objectives.

Conclusion: The Impact of Government Actions on Externalities

In summary, this article has explored the crucial role of government actions in addressing externalities. We've examined how policies like taxes, subsidies, and regulations can help internalize external costs and benefits. Understanding these interventions is vital for grasping the complexities of modern economies and environmental challenges. The government's impact on externalities affects various sectors, from pollution control to public health initiatives. To fully grasp these concepts, we encourage you to revisit the introduction video, which provides a comprehensive overview of the topic. As externalities continue to shape our world, staying informed about government policies and their effects is essential. We invite you to engage further with this subject by exploring additional resources, participating in local policy discussions, or even considering how externalities affect your daily life. Your understanding and involvement can contribute to more effective solutions for societal and environmental challenges.

Government Actions in Externalities Overview

Government Actions in Externalities Overview How Government Regulates Negative Externalities

  • Property Rights
  • Taxes
  • Emissions Charges
  • Cap-and-Trade

Step 1: Property Rights

The first method the government can use to regulate negative externalities is by establishing property rights. By doing so, the government confronts producers with the costs of their actions. For instance, if a producer is causing pollution, the property rights will make them acknowledge and pay for these external costs. This incentivizes producers to change the quantity supplied to account for these costs. Economically, this is represented by a shift in the supply curve to the left, reflecting the marginal social cost curve. This adjustment leads to a new market equilibrium where the external costs are acknowledged, resulting in a more efficient market outcome.

Step 2: Taxes

Another method is the imposition of taxes. If the government sets a tax equal to the external cost, the firm will have to pay both the tax and the private marginal cost. This effectively makes the firm's cost curve align with the marginal social cost curve. Graphically, this is shown by adding the tax to the marginal private cost, resulting in a new equilibrium where the firm produces less, thus internalizing the external cost. This method ensures that the firm reduces its production to a level that reflects the true social cost of its activities.

Step 3: Emissions Charges

Emissions charges are another tool the government can use. Instead of a blanket tax, the government sets a price per unit of pollution. For example, if the price per unit of pollution is $10 and a firm produces 50 units, the firm would have to pay $500 in emissions charges. This method directly ties the cost to the amount of pollution produced, incentivizing firms to reduce their emissions. The more pollution a firm produces, the higher the charges, which encourages firms to minimize their pollution to reduce costs.

Step 4: Cap-and-Trade

The cap-and-trade system involves the government assigning permits that set a cap on the amount of pollution a firm can produce. Each firm receives a different permit based on their needs, and these permits can be traded among firms. For instance, if Firm A has a permit for 40 units but only needs 30, it can trade with Firm B, which needs more. This system ensures that the total pollution remains within a set limit while allowing firms flexibility in how they meet their production needs. Firms will trade permits until the marginal pollution cost equals the price of the permit, ensuring an efficient allocation of pollution rights.

FAQs

  1. What are externalities and why are they important in economics?

    Externalities are the unintended effects of economic activities on third parties not directly involved in the transaction. They are important because they can lead to market inefficiencies. Positive externalities, like education, create benefits for society beyond the individual, while negative externalities, such as pollution, impose costs on society. Understanding and addressing externalities is crucial for achieving optimal resource allocation and maximizing social welfare.

  2. How do governments address negative externalities?

    Governments address negative externalities through various methods, including:

    • Taxes (e.g., carbon taxes) to increase the cost of harmful activities
    • Regulations to limit or control activities causing externalities
    • Cap-and-trade systems to create a market for emission rights
    • Establishing and enforcing property rights to allow for private negotiations
    These approaches aim to internalize the external costs and align private incentives with social costs.

  3. What methods do governments use to promote positive externalities?

    To promote positive externalities, governments typically use:

    • Subsidies to reduce the cost of beneficial activities
    • Direct public provision of goods or services (e.g., public education)
    • Vouchers to support consumption while maintaining consumer choice
    • Tax incentives for activities that generate positive externalities
    These methods aim to increase the production or consumption of goods and services that benefit society as a whole.

  4. How do pollution taxes work to address negative externalities?

    Pollution taxes work by increasing the cost of polluting activities to match their true social cost. This is done by imposing a tax equal to the external cost per unit of pollution. Graphically, this shifts the supply curve upward, aligning it with the marginal social cost curve. As a result, the market reaches a new equilibrium where the price reflects both private and social costs, leading to reduced production of the polluting good and incentivizing cleaner production methods.

  5. What are the challenges in implementing government actions on externalities?

    Implementing government actions on externalities faces several challenges:

    • Accurately measuring the value of externalities
    • Determining the optimal level of intervention (tax, subsidy, or regulation)
    • Balancing economic efficiency with political and social considerations
    • Avoiding unintended consequences, such as industry relocation or over-reliance on government support
    • Ensuring compliance and effective enforcement of policies
    Policymakers must carefully consider these factors to design effective and appropriate interventions.

Prerequisite Topics

Understanding government actions in externalities is a crucial aspect of economics and public policy. While there are no specific prerequisite topics provided for this subject, it's important to recognize that a strong foundation in basic economic principles and market dynamics is essential for grasping the complexities of government interventions in cases of externalities.

To fully comprehend government actions in externalities, students should have a solid understanding of fundamental economic concepts. These include supply and demand, market equilibrium, and the basic principles of microeconomics. Familiarity with these topics allows students to better analyze how externalities disrupt market efficiency and why government intervention may be necessary.

Additionally, knowledge of market failures is crucial when studying government actions in externalities. Externalities are a type of market failure, and understanding how markets can fail to allocate resources efficiently provides context for government interventions. This background helps students appreciate why governments might choose to take action in certain situations.

A grasp of public policy and governance is also beneficial when exploring this topic. Understanding how governments function, make decisions, and implement policies provides insight into the mechanisms used to address externalities. This knowledge helps students evaluate the effectiveness and potential consequences of various government actions.

Furthermore, familiarity with environmental economics can be particularly useful, as many examples of externalities and government interventions relate to environmental issues. Concepts such as pollution, resource depletion, and sustainability often come into play when discussing externalities and government responses.

While not strictly prerequisites, having a background in game theory and behavioral economics can enhance students' understanding of how different actors respond to externalities and government interventions. These fields provide insights into strategic decision-making and human behavior, which are relevant when analyzing the effects of government actions on individuals and firms.

Lastly, a basic understanding of policy instruments such as taxes, subsidies, and regulations is helpful. These are common tools used by governments to address externalities, and familiarity with their mechanics and potential impacts aids in evaluating their appropriateness and effectiveness in different scenarios.

By building a strong foundation in these related areas, students will be better equipped to analyze and critically evaluate government actions in externalities. This comprehensive understanding allows for more nuanced discussions and insights into the complex interplay between market forces, externalities, and government interventions in modern economies.

How Government Regulates Negative Externalities

The government can take action against negative externalities in three ways
  1. Property Rights: By establishing these rights, we can confront producers with the costs of their actions. This gives them incentive to change the quantity supplied.

    Economically, firms realize their actions and external cost so their private MC curve becomes the MSC curve.

  2. How Government Regulates Negative Externalities  Property Rights
  3. Taxes: If the government sets a tax equal to the external cost, then the firm will have to pay both the private marginal cost and tax. This leads to the firms supply to be the marginal social cost. In other words,
  4. MPC + tax = MSC

  5. Emission Charges: The government sets a price per unit of pollution. The more pollution the firm makes, the more emissions charges the firm must pay. This is an alternative to taxes.

  6. Cap-And-Trade: The government assigns a permit which tells you the cap (pollution quota) of the firm. Each permit may be different for each firm.

    Note: firms trade permits until the marginal pollution cost is equal to the price of the permit.

Using Pollution Tax for Negative Externalities

Recall that the firms supply curve is the MPC curve.

S0 = MPC

We also have the demand curve MSD. When a pollution tax is implemented, we add the tax to the MPC curve. Thus, the firms supply curve is now

S1 = MPC + tax

Since the tax is equal to the external cost, then we also notice that

MSC = S1

Thus, the new market equilibrium is at the intersection of S1 and MSD curve.

Using Pollution Tax for Negative Externalities

How Government Regulates Positive Externalities

The government can take action against positive externalities in four ways:
  1. Public Production:: When the government implements public production, consumers realize the external benefits, thus changing their private MPB curve to the MSB curve. This achieves efficient market equilibrium

  2. How Government Regulates Positive Externalities  Public Production

  3. Subsidies: a government payment that is made to producers. By adding subsidies, the firms supply curve becomes

  4. S = MPC - Subsidy

    Since the product is cheaper to produce, firms produce more to compensate for the underproduction from external benefits.

  5. Vouchers: a token that is provided from the government and given to households. Consumer realizes the extra benefit gained from the token, and so the marginal private demand becomes the marginal social demand.

  6. How Government Regulates Positive Externalities  Vouchers

Using Subsidies for Positive Externalities

Recall that the firms supply curve S0 is the MPC curve, and the demand curve is MPD.

Suppose MSC = MPC. When subsidy is implemented, we subtract the subsidy from the MPC. Thus, the firms supply curve is now

S1 = MPC - Subsidy

Thus, the new market equilibrium is at the intersection of S1 and MPD curve.

Using Subsidies for Positive Externalities