Mastering Short & Long Run Macroeconomic Equilibrium
Dive into the dynamics of short and long-run macroeconomic equilibrium. Understand how economic shocks affect output, and explore the adjustment process towards long-term stability. Perfect for economics students!

  1. Intros0/4 watched
  1. 0/4
Now Playing:Short and long run macroeconomic equilibrium – Example 0a
Intros
0/4 watched
  1. Short Run Macroeconomic Equilibrium
    • Intersection of AS and AD curve
    • Real GDP demand = Real GDP supplied
    • Price level above Equilibrium
    • Price level below Equilibrium
  2. Long Run Macroeconomic Equilibrium
    • Long-run Aggregate Supply
    • Full Employment
    • Price level above Long-run Equilibrium
    • Price level below Long-run Equilibrium
Aggregate supply
Notes


Short Run Macroeconomic Equilibrium

The short-run macroeconomic equilibrium happens when

SASq=ADqSAS_{q} = AD_{q}


Where:
ADqAD_{q} \, \, quantity of real GDP demanded
SASqSAS_{q} \, \, quantity of real GDP supplied in the short run

Graphically, this happens when the short-run aggregate supply and aggregate demand intersects

Short & Long Run Macroeconomic Equilibrium


The intersection gives us the price level.

If the price level is not at the equilibrium, then there are two possible cases.

Case 1: The price level is above the short-run equilibrium price level.

Short & Long Run Macroeconomic Equilibrium


In this case, the firms are not able to sell all their outputs due to the excess in supply. Since remaining outputs get stockpiled, firms would eventually have to cut production until all their output is sold. Eventually, we go back to the equilibrium.

Case 2: The price level is below the short-run equilibrium price level.

Short & Long Run Macroeconomic Equilibrium


In this case, the firms are not able to meet the demand due to the shortage of outputs. The firms would have to increase production and costs to meet the demand of outputs they need. Eventually, we go back to the equilibrium.

Note: Recall that in the short run, money wage rate is fixed so it is possible that real GDP is greater or less than potential GDP.

Long Run Macroeconomic Equilibrium

The long-run macroeconomic equilibrium happens when potential GDP is equal to real GDP, and full employment is reached (unemployment rate = natural rate of unemployment). Equivalently, it happens when

SASq=ADq=LASqSAS_{q} = AD_{q} =LAS_{q}


Where:
ADqAD_{q} \, \, quantity of real GDP demanded
SASqSAS_{q} \, \, quantity of real GDP supplied in the short run
LASqLAS_{q} \, \, quantity of real GDP supplied in the long run

Graphically, this is when the short-run aggregate supply, long-run aggregate supply, and aggregate demand all intersect.

Short & Long Run Macroeconomic Equilibrium


What if the price level is currently not at the long-run macroeconomic equilibrium? The idea is that eventually the price level will always go the long-run equilibrium price level.

Let’s look at 2 cases.

Case 1: The short-run equilibrium price level is above the long-run equilibrium price level.

Short & Long Run Macroeconomic Equilibrium


The money wage rate is very high, and unemployment rate > natural rate of unemployment. High money wage rate causes workers to supply more labor. So SAS0 SAS_{0} shifts right, becoming SAS1 SAS_{1} , and the price level is now at the long-run equilibrium price level.

Case 2: The short-run equilibrium price level is below the long-run equilibrium price level.

Short & Long Run Macroeconomic Equilibrium


The money wage rate is very low, and unemployment rate < natural rate of unemployment. Low money wage rate causes workers to supply less labor. So SAS0 SAS_{0} shifts left, becoming SAS1 SAS_{1} , and the price level is now at the long-run equilibrium price level.

Economic Growth & Inflation with AS-AD Model

Economic Growth & Inflation: When potential GDP increases from labor productivity and growth of labor, the LAS curve shifts to right. Inflation in the economy causes the AD curve to shift to the right.

There are 3 types of ways the AD curve and LAS curve can shift.

Case 1: Inflation growth rate > GDP growth rate. So, the AD curve shifts more than the LAS curve, causing an increase in the price level.

Short & Long Run Macroeconomic Equilibrium


This results in an inflation to the price level.

Case 2: Inflation growth rate = GDP growth rate. So, the AD curve shifts the same amount as the LAS curve, causing neither an increase nor decrease to the price level.

Short & Long Run Macroeconomic Equilibrium


This results in no changes to the price level.

Case 3: Inflation growth rate < GDP growth rate. So, the AD curve shifts less than the LAS curve, causing a decrease in the price level.

Short & Long Run Macroeconomic Equilibrium


This results in a deflation to the price level.

Business Cycle with AS-AD Model

Recall that the output gap is the difference between real GDP and potential GDP. An output gap can either be inflationary or recessionary.

Case 1: When real GDP = potential GDP, there is an no output gap. The AS curve and AD curve intersects on the LAS curve.

Short & Long Run Macroeconomic Equilibrium


We achieve full-employment equilibrium (unemployment rate = natural rate of unemployment).

Case 2: When real GDP > potential GDP, there is an inflationary gap. The AS curve and AD curve intersects at the right of the LAS curve.

Short & Long Run Macroeconomic Equilibrium


We achieve above full-employment equilibrium (unemployment rate < natural rate of unemployment).

Case 3: When real GDP < potential GDP, there is a recessionary gap. The AS curve and AD curve intersects at the left of the LAS curve.

Short & Long Run Macroeconomic Equilibrium


We achieve below full-employment equilibrium (unemployment rate > natural rate of unemployment).
Concept

Introduction to Short & Long Run Macroeconomic Equilibrium

Welcome to our exploration of macroeconomic equilibrium! In this section, we'll dive into the fascinating world of short-run and long-run equilibrium. As your friendly math tutor, I'm excited to guide you through these essential concepts. Our introduction video sets the stage perfectly, offering a clear visual representation of how aggregate supply and aggregate demand interact in different time frames. In the short run, we'll see how the economy can deviate from its potential output due to various shocks. This is where prices and wages might be sticky, leading to temporary imbalances. As we transition to the long run, you'll discover how these imbalances eventually correct themselves, with the economy returning to its natural rate of output. Understanding these dynamics is crucial for grasping broader economic trends and policy implications. So, let's embark on this journey together, unraveling the intricacies of macroeconomic equilibrium!

Example

Short Run Macroeconomic Equilibrium

  • Intersection of AS and AD curve
  • Real GDP demand = Real GDP supplied
  • Price level above Equilibrium
  • Price level below Equilibrium

Step 1: Understanding Short-Run Macroeconomic Equilibrium

Short-run macroeconomic equilibrium occurs when the short-run aggregate supply (SAS) curve intersects with the aggregate demand (AD) curve. This intersection point signifies that the quantity of real GDP demanded is equal to the quantity of real GDP supplied. In other words, the economy is in a state where the total output produced by firms matches the total demand from consumers, businesses, and the government.

Step 2: Graphical Representation

To visualize short-run macroeconomic equilibrium, we use a graph where the SAS curve and the AD curve intersect. For instance, if the equilibrium occurs at a real GDP of 11 trillion and a price level of 100, this point on the graph represents the short-run equilibrium. The intersection of these curves not only shows the equilibrium quantity but also determines the equilibrium price level.

Step 3: Price Level Above Equilibrium

When the price level is above the equilibrium, say at 120 instead of 100, the economy experiences an excess supply. At this higher price level, goods and services become more expensive, leading to a decrease in demand. Consequently, firms produce more than what is demanded, resulting in an excess supply. For example, if firms produce 12 trillion worth of goods but only 10 trillion is demanded, the excess 2 trillion worth of goods will be stockpiled. Over time, firms will reduce production to clear out the excess inventory, leading to a decrease in the price level until equilibrium is restored.

Step 4: Price Level Below Equilibrium

Conversely, when the price level is below the equilibrium, say at 90 instead of 100, the economy faces a shortage of supply. At this lower price level, goods and services are cheaper, increasing demand. However, firms are less willing to supply at these lower prices because it is less profitable. This results in a shortage where demand exceeds supply. For instance, if the demand is for 12 trillion worth of goods but only 10 trillion is supplied, firms will eventually increase production to meet the higher demand. This increase in production will raise the price level until it reaches the equilibrium point.

Step 5: Adjustments to Equilibrium

The economy naturally adjusts to restore equilibrium when the price level is either above or below the equilibrium. If the price level is above equilibrium, the excess supply will lead to a reduction in production and a decrease in prices. If the price level is below equilibrium, the shortage will lead to an increase in production and an increase in prices. These adjustments ensure that the economy returns to a state where the quantity of real GDP demanded equals the quantity of real GDP supplied.

Step 6: Conclusion

In summary, short-run macroeconomic equilibrium is achieved when the SAS and AD curves intersect, indicating that real GDP demanded equals real GDP supplied. The economy may experience periods where the price level is above or below this equilibrium, leading to excess supply or shortage, respectively. However, through natural market adjustments, the economy will eventually return to equilibrium. Understanding these dynamics is crucial for analyzing economic conditions and making informed policy decisions.

FAQs
  1. What is the difference between short-run and long-run macroeconomic equilibrium?

    Short-run macroeconomic equilibrium occurs when aggregate demand (AD) equals short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) at a specific price level and output. This equilibrium can deviate from the economy's potential output due to sticky prices and wages. Long-run macroeconomic equilibrium, on the other hand, represents a state where the economy has fully adjusted to all shocks, and actual output equals potential output. In the long run, all prices and wages are flexible, allowing the economy to return to its natural rate of output.

  2. How does the output gap relate to macroeconomic equilibrium?

    The output gap is the difference between actual output and potential output. It's closely related to macroeconomic equilibrium: - No output gap: The economy is at long-run equilibrium, operating at full potential. - Positive output gap (inflationary gap): Actual output exceeds potential, indicating short-run equilibrium above long-run equilibrium. - Negative output gap (recessionary gap): Actual output is below potential, suggesting short-run equilibrium below long-run equilibrium. Understanding the output gap helps policymakers determine appropriate economic interventions.

  3. How do economic shocks affect short-run and long-run equilibrium?

    Economic shocks can cause deviations from equilibrium in both the short and long run. In the short run, shocks (like sudden changes in consumer spending or oil prices) can shift the AD or SRAS curves, leading to a new short-run equilibrium. In the long run, the economy adjusts to these shocks through price and wage flexibility, returning to its potential output level. However, some shocks (like technological advancements) can also affect long-run equilibrium by shifting the long-run aggregate supply curve.

  4. What role does inflation play in the ASAD model?

    Inflation is represented in the ASAD model through changes in the price level. In the short run, inflation can result from shifts in AD or SRAS curves. Persistent inflation expectations can cause the SRAS curve to shift, affecting short-run equilibrium. In the long run, the relationship between inflation and economic growth is crucial. When inflation rates exceed GDP growth rates, it can lead to stagflation. Ideally, economies aim for a scenario where the inflation rate is slightly less than the GDP growth rate, promoting sustainable economic growth.

  5. How do policymakers use macroeconomic equilibrium models in decision-making?

    Policymakers use macroeconomic equilibrium models to guide economic decisions: - Short-run models help in crafting immediate responses to economic fluctuations, such as implementing fiscal stimulus during recessions. - Long-run models inform strategies for sustainable economic growth, like investments in education and infrastructure. - Central banks use these models to set monetary policy, balancing short-term economic stabilization with long-term price stability and employment goals. - Governments use them to assess the potential impacts of major policy changes, such as trade agreements or environmental regulations.

Prerequisites

Understanding short and long run macroeconomic equilibrium is a crucial aspect of economics that requires a solid foundation in various economic concepts. While there are no specific prerequisite topics provided for this subject, it's important to recognize that a comprehensive grasp of fundamental economic principles is essential for mastering this complex area of study.

To fully appreciate the intricacies of short and long run macroeconomic equilibrium, students should have a strong understanding of basic economic theories and models. These foundational concepts serve as building blocks for more advanced topics in macroeconomics. For instance, familiarity with supply and demand dynamics is crucial, as these forces play a significant role in determining equilibrium in both the short and long run.

Additionally, knowledge of aggregate demand and aggregate supply is vital for comprehending macroeconomic equilibrium. These concepts help explain how the overall economy behaves and how various factors can influence economic output and price levels. Understanding the components of aggregate demand, such as consumption, investment, government spending, and net exports, provides valuable insights into the forces that drive economic equilibrium.

Another important area to be well-versed in is the concept of economic growth and business cycles. These topics are closely related to short and long run macroeconomic equilibrium, as they help explain how economies fluctuate over time and eventually reach stable states. Familiarity with factors affecting economic growth, such as technological progress and capital accumulation, can enhance one's understanding of long-run equilibrium.

Moreover, a solid grasp of monetary and fiscal policies is essential for analyzing how government interventions can impact macroeconomic equilibrium. Understanding how interest rates, money supply, and government spending influence economic outcomes is crucial for comprehending the mechanisms that drive equilibrium adjustments in both the short and long run.

While specific prerequisite topics are not provided, it's clear that a well-rounded understanding of fundamental economic principles is necessary for mastering short and long run macroeconomic equilibrium. Students should focus on building a strong foundation in these areas to ensure they can effectively analyze and interpret the complex interactions that occur in macroeconomic systems.

By dedicating time to studying these underlying concepts, students will be better equipped to tackle the challenges presented by short and long run macroeconomic equilibrium. This comprehensive approach will not only enhance their understanding of this specific topic but also provide a solid framework for exploring other advanced areas of economics in the future.